The Emergence of Conventions- The Crossroads Game: Difference between revisions

From Dickinson College Wiki
Jump to navigationJump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
 
(32 intermediate revisions by 3 users not shown)
Line 2: Line 2:




Consider the following example (after a model by Dr Dieter Schmidtchen and a model by Dr. Bertrand Lemennicier  
Consider the following example (after a model by Dr Dieter Schmidtchen [[Sources| [9]]] and a model by Dr. Bertrand Lemennicier [[Sources| [33]]].


[http://www.uni-saarland.de/fak1/fr12/csle/persons/ps.htm More on Dr. Schmidtchen]
[http://www.uni-saarland.de/fak1/fr12/csle/persons/ps.htm More on Dr. Schmidtchen]
Line 9: Line 9:




. Suppose that you, Driver 1 (D 1) are approaching an intersection. Another car driving in the opposite direction by Driver 2 (D 2) gets at the intersection at the same time.  
Suppose that a random driver, Driver 1 (D 1) is approaching an intersection. Another car driving in the opposite direction by Driver 2 (D 2) gets at the intersection at the same time.  




Since you both have to cross the intersection, you as D1 have two options: you can either slow down (strategy S) and let the other car pass or you can maintain speed (strategy M).  Suppose D 1 has an expectation of ? that D 2 will slow down and an expectation of 1 - ? that D 2 will maintain speed,  where ? ? (0.1) Suppose D 2 has an expectation of ? that D 1 will slow down and an expectation of 1 - ? that  D 1 will maintain speed, where ? ? (0.1).  
Since both drivers have to cross the intersection, D 1 has two options: he can either slow down (strategy S) and let the other car pass or he can maintain speed (strategy M).  Suppose D 1 has an expectation of ? that D 2 will slow down and an expectation of 1 - ? that D 2 will maintain speed,  where ? ? (0.1) Suppose D 2 has an expectation of ? that D 1 will slow down and an expectation of 1 - ? that  D 1 will maintain speed, where ? ? (0.1).  




Below are the payoffs measured in the time drivers lose at the intersection. If one of the drivers slows down and the other one maintains speed, the one who slowed down will lose one minute. If both drivers slow down, they will each lose 10 minutes, as they have to decide who will gain priority in crossing the road (although 10 minutes is clearly exaggerated, assume that number of minutes for the purpose of this game). If both drivers maintain speed, they will collide, which will result in each one losing 21 minutes (assess and agree on the damages, exchange insurance information, etc.), in addition  to later on having to incur some cost for repairing their cars.  
Below are the payoffs measured in the time drivers lose at the intersection. Suppose that if one of the drivers slows down and the other one maintains speed, the one who slows down will lose one minute and that if both drivers slow down, they will each lose 10 minutes, as they have to decide who will gain priority in crossing the road. Also, suppose that if both drivers maintain speed (and thus collide), they will each lose 21 minutes (assess and agree on the damages, exchange insurance information, etc.), in addition  to later on having to incur some cost for repairing their cars.  




Line 21: Line 21:




Assume that the game is played by a very large number of drivers, who have to encounter this situation very often. The players do not know each other’s actions (i.e. the game is not valid if one of the drivers maintains speed as he knows that the other driver will slow down, due to the fact that he has preveiously encountered him). The only thing known to the players is the game’s payoffs.  
Assume that the game is played by a very large number of drivers, who have to encounter this situation very often. The players cannot predict each other’s actions (i.e. the game is not valid if one of the drivers maintains speed as he knows that the other driver will slow down, due to the fact that he has previously encountered him). The only thing known to the players is the game’s payoffs.
 
 
'''Expected Losses for D 1'''
 


The expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy M is:
The expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy M is:


EM = (1- ?)(21) + (?)(0)  ,  which can be translated as 21 times D 1’s expectation that D 2 will maintain speed (1- ?) + 0 times D 1’s expectation that D 2 will slow down (?)
EM 1 = (1- ?)(21) + (?)(0)  ,  ( D 1's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver maintains speed as well + D 1's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver slows down)
 


The expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy S is:
The expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy S is:


ES = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10)
ES 1 = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10) , ( D 1's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver maintains speed + D 1's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver slows down as well)
 
 
'''Expected Losses for D 2'''




The expected loss for D 2 from adopting strategy M is:
The expected loss for D 2 from adopting strategy M is:


EM = (1- ?)(21) + (?)(0)
EM 2 = (1- ?)(21) + (?)(0), ( D 2's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver maintains speed as well + D 2's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver slows down)
 


The expected loss for D 2 from adopting strategy S is:
The expected loss for D 2 from adopting strategy S is:


ES = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10)
ES 2 = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10), ( D 2's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver maintains speed + D 2's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver slows down as well)




'''Analysis for D 1'''
'''Analysis for D 1'''


The decision on which strategy to adopt depends on each driver’s expectations on what the other driver will do. If, for example, ? = 1, which means that D 1 completely expects D 2 to slow down, D 1 will maintain speed, as his incurred losses will equal 0. If however,  ? = 0, which means that D 1 completely expects D 2 to maintain speed,  D 1 will slow down as the losses of him slowing down (1 minute) are smaller than the losses of him maintaining speed (21 minutes).   
The decision on which strategy to adopt depends on each driver’s expectations on what the other driver will do.  
 
'''a'''. if ? = 1, which means that D 1 completely expects D 2 to slow down, D 1 will maintain speed, as his incurred losses will equal 0.  
 
 
'''b'''. if ? = 0, which means that D 1 completely expects D 2 to maintain speed,  D 1 will slow down as the losses of him slowing down (1 minute) are smaller than the losses of him maintaining speed (21 minutes).   
 
 
'''c'''. if D 1 expects D 2 to have an equal chance of maintaining speed or slowing down (which means that ? = 1/2):
 
EM 1 = (1- 1/2)(21) + (1/2)(0)
EM 1 = 21/2 + 0/2 = 10.5
 
 
ES 1 = (1- 1/2)(1) + (1/2)(10)
ES 1 = 1/2 = 5.5


Supposing that D 1 expects D 2 to have an equal chance of maintaining speed or slowing down,
Since EM 1 > ES 2,  D 1 will always maintain speed when he expects D 2 to have an equal chance of maintaining speed or slowing down


EM = 21/2 + 0/2 = 10.5


ES = 10/2 + 1/2 = 5.5
'''d'''. if D 1 is indifferent between slowing down and maintaining speed as the expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy M equals the expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy S


Since EM > ES,  D 1 will always maintain speed
EM 1 = ES 1


Driver D 1 will be indifferent between slowing down and maintaining speed when EM = ES , which will happen when the expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy M equals the expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy S, which means that EM = ES .
1-?)(21) + (?)(0) = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10)


(1- ?)(21) + (?)(0) = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10)
?= 2/3= 0.67
?= 2/3= 0.67


Line 64: Line 88:


Same as analysis for D 1. When ?< 0.67 D 2 should maintain speed and when ?> 0.67 D 2 should slow down.  
Same as analysis for D 1. When ?< 0.67 D 2 should maintain speed and when ?> 0.67 D 2 should slow down.  




'''Nash Equilibria of the Game'''
'''Nash Equilibria of the Game'''


There are three combinations (?,?) in which no tendency of change in probabilities arise: (0,1), (1,0) and (0.67, 0.67). While (0,1) and (1,0)are stable equilibria, (0.67, 0.67)is un unstable equilibriumas seem in the figure below:
There are three combinations (?,?) in which no tendency of change in probabilities arise: (0,1), (1,0) and (0.67, 0.67). While (0,1) and (1,0)are stable equilibria (both drivers clearly know what to expect from each other), (0.67, 0.67) is un unstable equilibrium as drivers don't clearly know what to expect from each other since they are indifferent between speeding and slowing down.




Line 74: Line 99:




Let x1 = probability of D 1 to maintain speed and x2 = probability of D 1 to slow down  
Let x1 = probability that D 1 maintains speed and x2 = probability that D 1 slows down  


Let y1 = probability of D 2 to maintain speed and y2 = probability of D 2 to slow down  
Let y1 = probability of D 2 maintains speed and y2 = probability of D 2 slows down  


Both drivers want to minimize their expected losses  
 
Both drivers want to minimize their expected losses
 
D 1’s expected losses = x1 (EM 1) + X2 (ES 1)


D 1’s expected losses = x1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]  
D 1’s expected losses = x1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]  


D2’s expected losses= y1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + y2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]


A Nash equilibria will consist of probabilities (x1, x2, y1, y2), where x1 = ? and x2= 1- ?
D2’s expected losses = y1 (EM 2) + y2 (ES 2)
 
D2’s expected losses = y1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + y2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]
 
 
A Nash equilibria will consist of probability beliefs (1-?, ?, 1-?, ?), probability of chosing probabilities (x1, x2, y1, y2), such that x1 = ?, y1 = ? and x1 = ? , x2= 1- ?  




Line 99: Line 131:




(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0) = £1 + £2
(1-?) (21) + (?)(0) = £1 + £2
(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10) = £1 + £3
(1-?) (1) + (?)(10) = £1 + £3


x1 + x2 = 1
x1 + x2 = 1
Line 109: Line 141:


(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10) = £1
(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10) = £1


Thus,  
Thus,  
Line 114: Line 147:
(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0) = (1- ?) (1) + (?)(10),  
(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0) = (1- ?) (1) + (?)(10),  


-20 ? = -30
20 ? = 30


? = 2/3
? = 2/3 (thus the driver maintains speed two out of three times and slows down one out of three times) 


since x1 = ? , x2= 1- ?; x1 = 2/3, x2 = 1/3


Thus,as x1 = 2/3 and x2 = 1/3
Min(x1, x2) = x1 [(1- ?)(21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)] = 2/3 (1-2/3) (21) + 1/3 (1-2/3) = 7


x1 [(1- ?)(21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)] = 2/3 (1-2/3) (21) + 1/3 (1-2/3) = 7
Thus D 1 had an expected loss of 7  




Line 129: Line 163:


y1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + y2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]  = 7
y1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + y2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]  = 7
Using the above hypothesis, in 55.6 % of all interactions, drivers do not coordinate their movements, and 11.2% of the crossroads interactions would end up with accidents. While it might seem that there is no spontaneous interaction between drivers that is actually not the case. In order to reduce coordination problems, people have spontaneously adopted a natural order—road conventions (i.e. priority rules). For example, when driving on two roads of similar width, drivers tend to give priority to those drivers coming from the right. Spontaneous forces are also evident in the fact that drivers coming from a minor road slow down when having to pass a crossroad with a major road. Such conventions have not been invented by a rational, omniscient mind. Rather, they have evolved over time, as people realized that their risk of getting into accidents has diminished by respecting such unwritten laws.
The State’s role is to simply “improve” this natural order by using its power to coerce individuals to adapt to their behavior to spontaneously adopted rules. For example, fines can be given to those drivers who do not respect the priority rule. Also, the state can make it clear for the drivers when they should stop, which roads are minor, etc. It is important to recognize that the model employed cannot accurately predict the behavior of drivers; thus were the government to intervene based on this model, it would actually “force the real world into compliance with the abstract model"





Latest revision as of 13:52, 16 May 2006

Game theory can explain the emergence of road rules, as the outcome of two drivers passing each other depends on their spontaneous actions and not on a pre-designed system of rules.


Consider the following example (after a model by Dr Dieter Schmidtchen [9] and a model by Dr. Bertrand Lemennicier [33].

More on Dr. Schmidtchen

More on Dr. Lemennicier


Suppose that a random driver, Driver 1 (D 1) is approaching an intersection. Another car driving in the opposite direction by Driver 2 (D 2) gets at the intersection at the same time.


Since both drivers have to cross the intersection, D 1 has two options: he can either slow down (strategy S) and let the other car pass or he can maintain speed (strategy M). Suppose D 1 has an expectation of ? that D 2 will slow down and an expectation of 1 - ? that D 2 will maintain speed, where ? ? (0.1) Suppose D 2 has an expectation of ? that D 1 will slow down and an expectation of 1 - ? that D 1 will maintain speed, where ? ? (0.1).


Below are the payoffs measured in the time drivers lose at the intersection. Suppose that if one of the drivers slows down and the other one maintains speed, the one who slows down will lose one minute and that if both drivers slow down, they will each lose 10 minutes, as they have to decide who will gain priority in crossing the road. Also, suppose that if both drivers maintain speed (and thus collide), they will each lose 21 minutes (assess and agree on the damages, exchange insurance information, etc.), in addition to later on having to incur some cost for repairing their cars.


Description


Assume that the game is played by a very large number of drivers, who have to encounter this situation very often. The players cannot predict each other’s actions (i.e. the game is not valid if one of the drivers maintains speed as he knows that the other driver will slow down, due to the fact that he has previously encountered him). The only thing known to the players is the game’s payoffs.


Expected Losses for D 1


The expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy M is:

EM 1 = (1- ?)(21) + (?)(0) , ( D 1's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver maintains speed as well + D 1's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver slows down)


The expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy S is:

ES 1 = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10) , ( D 1's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver maintains speed + D 1's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver slows down as well)


Expected Losses for D 2


The expected loss for D 2 from adopting strategy M is:

EM 2 = (1- ?)(21) + (?)(0), ( D 2's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver maintains speed as well + D 2's expected loss for maintaining speed when the other driver slows down)


The expected loss for D 2 from adopting strategy S is:

ES 2 = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10), ( D 2's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver maintains speed + D 2's expected loss for slowing down when the other driver slows down as well)


Analysis for D 1

The decision on which strategy to adopt depends on each driver’s expectations on what the other driver will do.

a. if ? = 1, which means that D 1 completely expects D 2 to slow down, D 1 will maintain speed, as his incurred losses will equal 0.


b. if ? = 0, which means that D 1 completely expects D 2 to maintain speed, D 1 will slow down as the losses of him slowing down (1 minute) are smaller than the losses of him maintaining speed (21 minutes).


c. if D 1 expects D 2 to have an equal chance of maintaining speed or slowing down (which means that ? = 1/2):

EM 1 = (1- 1/2)(21) + (1/2)(0) EM 1 = 21/2 + 0/2 = 10.5


ES 1 = (1- 1/2)(1) + (1/2)(10) ES 1 = 1/2 = 5.5

Since EM 1 > ES 2, D 1 will always maintain speed when he expects D 2 to have an equal chance of maintaining speed or slowing down


d. if D 1 is indifferent between slowing down and maintaining speed as the expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy M equals the expected loss for D 1 from adopting strategy S

EM 1 = ES 1

1-?)(21) + (?)(0) = (1- ?)(1) + (?)(10)

?= 2/3= 0.67

Thus, when ?< 0.67 D 1 should maintain speed and when ?> 0.67 D 1 should slow down.


Analysis for D 2

Same as analysis for D 1. When ?< 0.67 D 2 should maintain speed and when ?> 0.67 D 2 should slow down.


Nash Equilibria of the Game

There are three combinations (?,?) in which no tendency of change in probabilities arise: (0,1), (1,0) and (0.67, 0.67). While (0,1) and (1,0)are stable equilibria (both drivers clearly know what to expect from each other), (0.67, 0.67) is un unstable equilibrium as drivers don't clearly know what to expect from each other since they are indifferent between speeding and slowing down.


Description


Let x1 = probability that D 1 maintains speed and x2 = probability that D 1 slows down

Let y1 = probability of D 2 maintains speed and y2 = probability of D 2 slows down


Both drivers want to minimize their expected losses

D 1’s expected losses = x1 (EM 1) + X2 (ES 1)

D 1’s expected losses = x1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]


D2’s expected losses = y1 (EM 2) + y2 (ES 2)

D2’s expected losses = y1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + y2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)]


A Nash equilibria will consist of probability beliefs (1-?, ?, 1-?, ?), probability of chosing probabilities (x1, x2, y1, y2), such that x1 = ?, y1 = ? and x1 = ? , x2= 1- ?


For Driver 1 :

Min(x1, x2) = x1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)], where x1 + x2 = 1

The Lagrangian takes the form:

L = x1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)] - £ (x1 +x2 -1) - £2x1 - £3x2


When differentiating with respect to x1 and x2 we get the following results:


(1-?) (21) + (?)(0) = £1 + £2 (1-?) (1) + (?)(10) = £1 + £3

x1 + x2 = 1

£2 = £3 = 0 which results in

(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0) = £1

(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10) = £1


Thus,

(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0) = (1- ?) (1) + (?)(10),

20 ? = 30

? = 2/3 (thus the driver maintains speed two out of three times and slows down one out of three times)

since x1 = ? , x2= 1- ?; x1 = 2/3, x2 = 1/3

Min(x1, x2) = x1 [(1- ?)(21) + (?)(0)] + x2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)] = 2/3 (1-2/3) (21) + 1/3 (1-2/3) = 7

Thus D 1 had an expected loss of 7


For Driver 2

same method as for Driver 1 leads to

y1 [(1- ?) (21) + (?)(0)] + y2 [(1- ?) (1) + (?)(10)] = 7


Using the above hypothesis, in 55.6 % of all interactions, drivers do not coordinate their movements, and 11.2% of the crossroads interactions would end up with accidents. While it might seem that there is no spontaneous interaction between drivers that is actually not the case. In order to reduce coordination problems, people have spontaneously adopted a natural order—road conventions (i.e. priority rules). For example, when driving on two roads of similar width, drivers tend to give priority to those drivers coming from the right. Spontaneous forces are also evident in the fact that drivers coming from a minor road slow down when having to pass a crossroad with a major road. Such conventions have not been invented by a rational, omniscient mind. Rather, they have evolved over time, as people realized that their risk of getting into accidents has diminished by respecting such unwritten laws.

The State’s role is to simply “improve” this natural order by using its power to coerce individuals to adapt to their behavior to spontaneously adopted rules. For example, fines can be given to those drivers who do not respect the priority rule. Also, the state can make it clear for the drivers when they should stop, which roads are minor, etc. It is important to recognize that the model employed cannot accurately predict the behavior of drivers; thus were the government to intervene based on this model, it would actually “force the real world into compliance with the abstract model"





General Overview | Major Contributors | Game Theory Models | Objections/Arguments | Sources