Important Economists: Difference between revisions
No edit summary |
No edit summary |
||
(39 intermediate revisions by 4 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
< | <center>[[Happiness in Economics|Home]] | [[Introduction to Happiness]] | [[Utility]] | [[Important Economists]] | [[Richard Layard]] | [[Layard's Lectures]] | [[Sweden]]</center> | ||
<big>'''Economists that Focus on Happiness in Economics'''</big> | |||
== Jeremy Bentham == | |||
<center> [[Image:Bentham.gif]] </center> | |||
Jeremy Bentham (1748-1832) was an English philosopher, jurist, and political theorist who was most well known for his concept of utilitarianism. He was a lawyer in the bar who never practiced, but rather Bentham came upon this theory because he dedicated his time to analyzing morals and legislation. Bentham believed in a free-market approach, and according to the Columbia Encyclopedia Bentham, “predated Keynes in his advocacy of expansionist monetary policies to achieve full employment and advocated a range of interventions, including the minimum wage and guaranteed employment.” | |||
Although the majority of his work was in ethics, his most lasting contributions were to economics and how his utilitarian principles applied to it. According to about.com utilitarianism can be defined as, “operating on the principle that the utility (happiness or satisfaction) of different people can not only be measured but also meaningfully summed over people and that utility comparisons between people are meaningful.” Bentham was best known for his statement concerning utilitarianism: “It is the greatest happiness of the greatest number that is the measure of right and wrong.” This lasting statement has been the basis of current happiness research because through his studies Bentham devised both quantitative and qualitative ways to measure happiness. He was a forerunner of happiness research through his lists of the sources of pleasure and pain, the use of the term “well-being,” and his subjective assessment of his research. He also suggested certain thoughts on happiness that “neo-Benthamites” and other economists work on solving today. | |||
''Notable Quotes about Bentham:'' | |||
"In the eighteenth century Bentham and others proposed that the object of public policy should be to maximize the sum of happiness in society. So economics evolved as the study of utility, or happiness, which was assumed to be in principle measurable and comparable across people." | |||
<br> "Bentham also believed that happiness matters because it is what people want. Indeed he argued that in the end all actions are driven by the desire to feel good." (Layard, 1st Lecture) | |||
This information was obtained through the website- http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Enc/bios/Bentham.html | |||
== Richard Easterlin== | == Richard Easterlin== | ||
<center> [[Image:Easterlin3.jpg]] </center> | |||
Richard Easterlin is known as the, “first economist to make prominent use of happiness data.” (Di Tella and MacCulloch). Easterlin, a well known economist, is currently an economics professor at the University of Southern California and has won many awards throughout his career for his economic papers and articles. Although he has many current papers on happiness, Easterlin first introduced his happiness research into the economic community in 1974. In an article from 2004 Easterlin focuses on topics first used by Bentham such as subjective well-being. He explores the subjective well-being through survey questions, the most common being, “How satisfied are you with your life as a whole – very, somewhat, so-so, not very, or not at all?” Easterlin, along with other economists, found this question to be very meaningful and useful when analyzing data. This is so because although it is a fairly simple question, people are generally willing to answer it, and when compared to factors such as their income and employment status, can be very informative. Easterlin argues that contrary to popular belief, “public policy measures aimed at increasing the income of society as a whole” will not necessary increase overall happiness. This has to do with the idea that happiness is relative; meaning that if one’s income increases they will feel happier than if everyone’s income also increases. Easterlin continues to research these themes of happiness within economics. | |||
This information was obtained through Richard Easterlin's personal website as well as from his article "The Economics of Happiness" | |||
[http://www-rcf.usc.edu/~easterl/index.html] | |||
[http://www.people.hbs.edu/rditella/papers/JEPHappyData.pdf article,Some uses of Happiness Data in Economics ] | [http://www.people.hbs.edu/rditella/papers/JEPHappyData.pdf article,Some uses of Happiness Data in Economics ] | ||
== Bruno Frey== | |||
<center> [[Image:Bsfrey.gif]] </center> | |||
[ | |||
Bruno Frey, a Swiss economist, is currently a professor at the University of Zurich. He is a highly published economist in a wide range of topics ranging from political economics, tax economics, and psychological economics. However, most importantly, Frey has provided the economic community with important happiness in economics research; 17 major articles this year alone. In his book Happiness & Economics Frey states that: | |||
<blockquote> Most economists take it as a matter of course that higher income leads to higher happiness. And why not? A higher income expands individuals' and countries' opportunity set; that is, more goods and services can be consumed. The few people not interested in more comodities need not consume them; they have the freedom to dispose of any unwanted surplus free of charge. It therefore seems obvious that income and happiness go together (provided, of course, that the two are correctly measured). Consequently, economics textbooks do not even make an effort to come up with a reason, but simply state that utility 'U' is raised by income 'Y'. </blockquote> | |||
He then goes on to discuss why these views of some other economists and textbooks may not be true through his research in his book as well as the 2002 article with Alois Stutzer ''What Can Economists Learn from Happiness Research?'' Frey maintains that there are certain paradoxes within this research such as the fact that although per capita income in the US rose by a factor of 2.5, in the same amount of time happiness stayed constant. He explores how happiness is affected by changes in income, employment, and inflation. A recurring theme of his research is the idea that having a higher income may not make a person happier, but on the converse, because someone is happy they work harder, and therefore make more money. He proposes many views to this research that sometimes differ from other economists. | |||
This information was obtained from his personal website http://www.bsfrey.ch/articles.html and his articles and book. | |||
== Robert H. Frank == | |||
<center> [[Image:RFrank.jpg]] </center> | |||
Robert Frank is a behavioral economist who is a Professor of Management and Economics at Cornell University as well as a regular columnist in the Economic View section of the New York Times. Frank is also a highly published author of several books, including a co-written textbook on economics. In his behavioral research, Frank also explores ideas of happiness in economics. However, Frank’s approach is somewhat different to that of his other happiness colleagues. Frank said that, “The changes in spending patterns prompted by recent changes in the distributions of income and wealth have imposed not only important psychological costs on middle-income families but also a variety of more tangible economic costs.” He focuses more on his ideas of income distribution amongst classes affecting happiness rather than approaching it from a broader sense of other researchers. Frank believes that “Large increases in income and wealth have promoted top earners to buy bigger and better.” This in turn trickles down to the other classes causing them to spend more and more, plunging into greater debt, thus becoming less happy. Frank poses questions about happiness in economics that present a different view than some, and is constantly sharing his findings within his articles and column. | |||
This information was obtained through the website- http://www.leighbureau.com/speaker.asp?id=416 | |||
Christie Wetzel compiled the information for this page. |
Latest revision as of 19:53, 10 December 2007
Economists that Focus on Happiness in Economics
Jeremy Bentham
Jeremy Bentham (1748-1832) was an English philosopher, jurist, and political theorist who was most well known for his concept of utilitarianism. He was a lawyer in the bar who never practiced, but rather Bentham came upon this theory because he dedicated his time to analyzing morals and legislation. Bentham believed in a free-market approach, and according to the Columbia Encyclopedia Bentham, “predated Keynes in his advocacy of expansionist monetary policies to achieve full employment and advocated a range of interventions, including the minimum wage and guaranteed employment.”
Although the majority of his work was in ethics, his most lasting contributions were to economics and how his utilitarian principles applied to it. According to about.com utilitarianism can be defined as, “operating on the principle that the utility (happiness or satisfaction) of different people can not only be measured but also meaningfully summed over people and that utility comparisons between people are meaningful.” Bentham was best known for his statement concerning utilitarianism: “It is the greatest happiness of the greatest number that is the measure of right and wrong.” This lasting statement has been the basis of current happiness research because through his studies Bentham devised both quantitative and qualitative ways to measure happiness. He was a forerunner of happiness research through his lists of the sources of pleasure and pain, the use of the term “well-being,” and his subjective assessment of his research. He also suggested certain thoughts on happiness that “neo-Benthamites” and other economists work on solving today.
Notable Quotes about Bentham:
"In the eighteenth century Bentham and others proposed that the object of public policy should be to maximize the sum of happiness in society. So economics evolved as the study of utility, or happiness, which was assumed to be in principle measurable and comparable across people."
"Bentham also believed that happiness matters because it is what people want. Indeed he argued that in the end all actions are driven by the desire to feel good." (Layard, 1st Lecture)
This information was obtained through the website- http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Enc/bios/Bentham.html
Richard Easterlin
Richard Easterlin is known as the, “first economist to make prominent use of happiness data.” (Di Tella and MacCulloch). Easterlin, a well known economist, is currently an economics professor at the University of Southern California and has won many awards throughout his career for his economic papers and articles. Although he has many current papers on happiness, Easterlin first introduced his happiness research into the economic community in 1974. In an article from 2004 Easterlin focuses on topics first used by Bentham such as subjective well-being. He explores the subjective well-being through survey questions, the most common being, “How satisfied are you with your life as a whole – very, somewhat, so-so, not very, or not at all?” Easterlin, along with other economists, found this question to be very meaningful and useful when analyzing data. This is so because although it is a fairly simple question, people are generally willing to answer it, and when compared to factors such as their income and employment status, can be very informative. Easterlin argues that contrary to popular belief, “public policy measures aimed at increasing the income of society as a whole” will not necessary increase overall happiness. This has to do with the idea that happiness is relative; meaning that if one’s income increases they will feel happier than if everyone’s income also increases. Easterlin continues to research these themes of happiness within economics.
This information was obtained through Richard Easterlin's personal website as well as from his article "The Economics of Happiness"
[1]
article,Some uses of Happiness Data in Economics
Bruno Frey
Bruno Frey, a Swiss economist, is currently a professor at the University of Zurich. He is a highly published economist in a wide range of topics ranging from political economics, tax economics, and psychological economics. However, most importantly, Frey has provided the economic community with important happiness in economics research; 17 major articles this year alone. In his book Happiness & Economics Frey states that:
Most economists take it as a matter of course that higher income leads to higher happiness. And why not? A higher income expands individuals' and countries' opportunity set; that is, more goods and services can be consumed. The few people not interested in more comodities need not consume them; they have the freedom to dispose of any unwanted surplus free of charge. It therefore seems obvious that income and happiness go together (provided, of course, that the two are correctly measured). Consequently, economics textbooks do not even make an effort to come up with a reason, but simply state that utility 'U' is raised by income 'Y'.
He then goes on to discuss why these views of some other economists and textbooks may not be true through his research in his book as well as the 2002 article with Alois Stutzer What Can Economists Learn from Happiness Research? Frey maintains that there are certain paradoxes within this research such as the fact that although per capita income in the US rose by a factor of 2.5, in the same amount of time happiness stayed constant. He explores how happiness is affected by changes in income, employment, and inflation. A recurring theme of his research is the idea that having a higher income may not make a person happier, but on the converse, because someone is happy they work harder, and therefore make more money. He proposes many views to this research that sometimes differ from other economists.
This information was obtained from his personal website http://www.bsfrey.ch/articles.html and his articles and book.
Robert H. Frank
Robert Frank is a behavioral economist who is a Professor of Management and Economics at Cornell University as well as a regular columnist in the Economic View section of the New York Times. Frank is also a highly published author of several books, including a co-written textbook on economics. In his behavioral research, Frank also explores ideas of happiness in economics. However, Frank’s approach is somewhat different to that of his other happiness colleagues. Frank said that, “The changes in spending patterns prompted by recent changes in the distributions of income and wealth have imposed not only important psychological costs on middle-income families but also a variety of more tangible economic costs.” He focuses more on his ideas of income distribution amongst classes affecting happiness rather than approaching it from a broader sense of other researchers. Frank believes that “Large increases in income and wealth have promoted top earners to buy bigger and better.” This in turn trickles down to the other classes causing them to spend more and more, plunging into greater debt, thus becoming less happy. Frank poses questions about happiness in economics that present a different view than some, and is constantly sharing his findings within his articles and column.
This information was obtained through the website- http://www.leighbureau.com/speaker.asp?id=416
Christie Wetzel compiled the information for this page.