Inflationary Expectations: Difference between revisions
Line 10: | Line 10: | ||
==The History of Inflation in the United States== | ==The History of Inflation in the United States== | ||
[[Image:cpi.gif]] | |||
==Inflationary Uncertainty== | ==Inflationary Uncertainty== |
Revision as of 05:58, 4 May 2006
It is hard to live in today's society and not be aware of inflation. Every year it makes the money we have stashed away in our mattresses worth less than it was last yaer. The inflation rate is therefore an important indicator that influences our general expectation for the future. Classically, inflation and unemployment are the two bugbears of macroeconomic policy. High inflation can seriously hurt an economy. At extreme levels, very high inflation is known as hyperinflation. This is bad for firms and consumers, but it's even worse for polititians.
So if everybody wants low inflation, why does it exist? One cause of inflation is inflationary expectations. We all have certain expectations for what the next year will bring. These expectations are usually based on the recent past. Therefore, if inflation has been very high the last couple of years, it may take a while for people to begin to expect lower inflation.
"So what?" you say. The problem is that through these inflationary expectations, people can actually cause inflation, whether other economic conditions predict it or not.
Inflation
Classical economic theory of inflation predicted a negative empirical relationship between unemployment and inflation. This relationsihp is known as the Phillips Curve. Such a relationship is an important concept with regard to economic policy. It means that policy makers can effectively force a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. For example, by increasing the monetary supply, the Federal Reserve Bank can influence the inflation rate, and therefore also the employment rate.
The History of Inflation in the United States
Inflationary Uncertainty
Policy Tools
External Links
Fed Credibility? What's the Big Deal?