China's Economic Growth and the Environment Fa 08

From Dickinson College Wiki
Revision as of 22:12, 23 November 2008 by Friscoj (talk | contribs)
Jump to navigationJump to search

China's Economic Growth

Economic Growth Overview (ryan)

History and Facts (ryan)

Environmental Impact

Health Effects(jenn)

Environmental Impact (maddie)

Kuznets Curve

Background

The environmental Kuznets curve (shown above) represents that concept that environmental degradation will decline once a country's per capita income reaches a certain level. The curve represents the hypothesized pattern that developing countries will follow as they grow. There is much controversy surrounding the validity and practicality of the environmental Kuznets curve.

In the beginning stages of a country's growth, industrialization occurs. During this, the curve shows that environmental damage grows rapidly. At this point people focus more on income, jobs, and improving the standard of living while pollution takes a back seat (Dasgupta 2002). The country is too poor to be able to fund and enforce pollution abatement and environmental regulation is nearly nonexistent. As per capita income rises, however, it reaches a turning point at which people are now able to address the concerns of the environment. Subsequently, new technologies are implemented and legislation is passed which results in environmental degradation falling. Initial estimates of the per capita level of income that represents the turning point range from $5000 to $8000 (Dasgupta 2002).

Controversy

The traditional environmental Kuznets curve applies mainly to water and air pollutants. Since not all types pollution has been found to decrease with a higher level of income, several opposing curves have emerged. As shown in the above figure, the creation of new pollutants as a country develops will stray from the original environmental Kuznets curve (Dasgupta 2002). In fact, these pollutants represented by the New Toxics curve will continue increasing as there is no means to eliminate them. The "Race to the Bottom" curve represents the idea that the curve will rise to a horizontal line at maximum pollution levels as globalization promotes a race to bottom in terms of environmental standards (Dasgupta 2002). The concept behind this is that businesses will flock to these developing countries who are unable to enforce environmental regulation as a way to cut costs by not complying with stricter regulation in other countries. The final alternative scenario is one where the turning point is lower and is reached with less pollution than the traditional curve. The inability to gather proper data in developing countries makes a conclusive argument for or against the validity of the environmental Kuznets curve difficult to reach.

Relating to China

China's gross domestic product (GDP) per capita in 2005 was $1702, well below the level where improvements in the environment should start to be seen (Backer 2007). This figure indicates that the next few decades should see continuing environmental damage in China. With World Bank estimates that mortality and sickness caused from urban air pollution represent a loss of 2-3% of GDP in China, the environmental Kuznets curve has received increased attention (Dasgupta 2002). As China continues to grow, regulation will become key in determining its environmental impact. Dasgupta et. al. argued three reasons why richer countries develop stricter pollution regulation. First, pollution becomes a higher priority after investments in health and education have been made. Second, richer countries have more funding to monitor and enforce regulations. Finally, higher income results in better education which increase awareness and demand by the public for regulation (Dasgupta 2002).

The Liberalization of an economy, as done in China, has been found to result in environmental improvements. When this occurs, government subsidies are often eliminated or reduced which most often benefits the environment (Dasgupta 2002). Subsidies typically are given to the heaviest polluters because those industries lend to state involvement. The elimination of subsidies will shift production to more efficient forms and also allow the free markets to guide firms towards more cost efficient methods These more efficient methods can also have a tendency of being environmentally friendly. As shown in Figure 3, the state-owned enterprises in China have much higher pollution abatement costs because they operate inefficiently (Dasgupta 2002).

China's Environmental Regulation Policies

Over the course of the last century China has undergone vast changes in social structure. There was the process of collectivization that lasted from 1949-1978 which was followed by market reform and decollectivization from 1978 to the present (Muldavin 2000). Throughout this time of rapid economic expansion, environmental damage has been profound and evironmental policy largely ineffective. Policy for the environment was typically discretionary and failed to address the causes of problems.

Collectivist Period

During the collectivist period China operated under a system of communal capital (Muldavin 2000). The state provided the means to transform production from private household-based to collective organization of production through redistribution of resources. Under this collective regime, people enjoyed little vulnerability when it came to providing for themselves (Muldavin 2000). Since they were under the protection of the state, they need not worry about going hungry if they had a bad harvest.

This period emphasized growth, regardless of the consequences. Environmental regulations were largely ignored and deemed insignificant compared to the goal of economic growth. It was not until 1972 that the environment became a concern (Muldavin 2000). This year saw a red tide in the Bay of Dalian cause shellfish production losses, fish in Beijing found to have toxic levels of chemicals, and a United Nations conference of health and the environment that encouraged China to develop environmental protection policies (Muldavin 2000). Attention was now brought to the status of the environment and the market reforms allowed more legislation to pass.

Market Reform

When China entered the market reform period beginning in 1978, a major change was the change of entitlement back to the individual (Muldavin 2000). Along with increased freedom came vulnerability and risk that had not been previously experienced. The result of not being able to rely on the state and needing to fend for oneself was environmental damage. The free-rider problem evolved into an open access problem and current regulation was not prepared to combat the ensuing environmental damage. People began to over-consume and exploit resources as a means of getting theirs before others could (Muldavin 2000). Forests were relentlessly cut, overgrazing occurred, and general disregard for the environment developed.

This period, however, also saw new environmental laws being ushered in. The first was the Environmental Protection Law in 1979, which increased regulation but environmental agencies still had little power (Muldavin 2000). Adding to the problem of enforcement was the redistribution of land to the people. This made it even harder to control what people were doing and limit environmental damage. China had finally became aware of the impact of environmental degradation and implemented policy, but simply thought that would be enough. The lack of enforcement and compliance standards made the regulations nearly irrelevant and China seemed to continue to be more concerned with growth, no matter the consequences.

Current Policy and Structure

The main governmental organization responsible for the environment in China is the State Environmental Protection Administration (SEPA), which is in charge of policy making and implementation (Backer 2007). SEPA was given more power in 1998 when its status change from an agency to administration. On the local basis, Environmental Protection Bureaus are responsible for implementing policy, but remain subordinate to the SEPA.

The United Nations Environmental Programme (UNEP) has played a significant role in getting China to address environmental concerns (Backer 2007). With the help of UNEP, China was able to see that environmental damages were resulting in significant losses of GDP each year. Global United Nations' conferences on the environment in 1972, 1992, and 2002 have also played roles in educating the Chinese government on the environment (Backer 2007). Each conference was taken more seriously as evidence by the increasing number of councils and non-governmental organizations preparing for them.

Now that China has begun to realize the impacts of its prolonged economic growth, it has started to address these concerns. While China seems to be significantly behind the rest of the world in terms of regulation, there is great outside pressure to catch up.

Suggestions for Improvement (all)

References

  • Backer E. and Heggelund G. (2007). China and UN environmental policy: institutional growth, learning and implementation. International Environmental Agreements : Politics, Law and Economics, 7(4), 415-438. Retrieved November 23, 2008, from ABI/INFORM Global database. (Document ID: 1394712261).
  • Dasgupta, S., et. al. "Confronting the Environmental Kuznets Curve." The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 16, No. 1 (2002), pp. 147-168.
  • Muldavin, J. "The Paradoxes of Environmental Policy and Resource Management in Reform-Era China." Economic Geography, Vol. 76, No. 3 (July 2000), pp. 244-271.