Hawk Dove Game and the Evolution of Property Rights

From Dickinson College Wiki
Revision as of 02:00, 28 April 2006 by 172.16.19.138 (talk)
Jump to navigationJump to search

The First Property Rights Revolution

Background

In their paper, The First Property Rights Revolution, Samual Bowles and Jung-Kyoo Choi attempt to explain the emergence of individual property rights, which replaced the "collectivist and egalitarian social structures" common to mobile foraging bands. A key element in this investigation is why property rights only emerged about 11,000 years ago with the domestication of plants and animals, and how they were able to evolve without the aid of states which did not appear until many millenia later. From archaological evidence and recent behavioral experiments it is clear that sharing norms existed as early as 100,000 years ago, and that the lives of these mobile hunter-gatherers were regulated by social norms and collective punishment of violators of these norms. These norms most likely applied to certain items, like large game, which were available sporadically and in large quantities.

"In these ... communities, group sanction emerged as the most powerful instrument for regulation of individually assertive behaviors, particularly those which obviously disrupted cooperation or disturbed social equilibrium needed for group stability."

In addition, humans are not unique in having property rights. Many species of spiders and the male Hamadryas baboons respect prior possession of sites and objects by individuals of the same species. These facts are puzzling in the face of explainations which present property rights as a way to minimize the waste from conflict, but cannot explain why property rights did not develop nearly 100,000 years earlier.

Approximately 11,000 years ago there was a significant climate change which allowed the domestication of plants and animals to become a feasible strategy. The process of transition to agriculture was gradual, but eventually replaced the social orders of all but a few hunter-gatherer bands. The connection between domestication and the emergence of property rights is that the possesion of land and livestock is relatively straight forward. There is likely to be little confusion as to whose land and animals are whose, versus a large animal that many people work together in different manners to kill. Also, successful agriculture required these rights to be in place in ordered to develop.

The Model

The model propose by Bowles and Choi is very similar to the Hawk-Dove-Bourgeois Game that we have seen in class. In the model there are n members of a foraging band who divide a good of value v. Individuals may adopt one of three strategies: grabbing (Hawk), sharing (Dove), or punishing (Bourgeois). When a Grabber meets a sharer they take the good. When a Grabber meets a Grabber they fight. They either gain the good or bear the cost of defeat, c>v, with equal probability. When a Punisher meets a Grabber, all the Punishers try to punish the Grabber. If they win, the good is distributed amongst all Punishers, or bear the cost of defeat c. The probability of successfully punishing a Grabber is equal to the population frequency of punisher, ?. If ? is the population frequency of Sharers, the payoffs are as follows: